Karl Marx and the ‘Wood Theft Law’
in 19th century Germany
It may not be surprising that the question of forest
rights and privileges has had a hoary and distinguished career in the world of
social-political thought and ideology. This is because forests have usually
been considered a part of the commons, open to anybody in the community for collecting the necessities of daily living, including fuel, food, fodder,
medicines, artisanal raw materials, etc. The moment forest administration is
put on a more organized basis under the direct control of state organs, this
direct and intimate relationship of community with commons is disrupted,
impinging on the day to day life (and misery) of the poorest people. Socially
conscious thinkers and activists, therefore, see in this a classical case of
the state usurping the space of the individual and the local community. A
discussion of forest policy, therefore, cannot be undertaken in a relatively
closed space, where only technical issues and concerns are taken into account,
as the professional forester is prone to do.
What may be a cause of surprise to most foresters (and
some environmentalists) is that one of the early social-political commentaries
on the forest situation is actually that of the great Karl Marx himself, and
that too in the earliest period of his career, even before he had formulated
his concept of historical materialism and the inevitable collapse of the
capitalist system. From October 1842 to the following January, faced with
growing government censorship in running the Rheinische Zeitung (RZ),
the young Marx turned "away from exclusive concentration on the philosophy of politics
and the politics of philosophy”, to certain
specific social and economic problems (Draper, 1977, Vol.I, p.66). Among these was the “Wood Theft Law”, a subject which “may strike the modern reader as
a tenth-rate problem” (compared with other pressing issues mentioned in the
chapter), but is “easily the most important that Marx wrote as editor” (Draper,
op. cit., p.63 onwards):
“Wood gathering had been a traditional right of the
peasants, but now when times were hard for them, the state was cracking down on
it. As a result of this collision between the needs of mass poverty and the
needs of property and business, prosecutions for wood theft had climbed
dramatically during the preceding decade… For example, around Trier {Marx’s hometown}, wood thefts formed an
amazing 97 percent of all thefts in the period 1830-1836 (for which there are
figures); in all Prussia in 1836, offenses in forest, hunting, and pasture
lands (probably mostly wood thefts and poaching) formed almost 77 percent of
all prosecutions. This situation continued until the 1848 revolution.” (Draper,
op. cit., p.63).
According to Draper, this is the first time that “we see
Marx caught up in a passionate identification with the poor and oppressed,
vividly feeling the misery and want he has investigated and trying to cry out
to the comfortable burghers: Look, here
are human beings suffering – something had to be done!” (Draper, op. cit.,
p.64). Draper supplies the following excerpt from the Rhenish historian H.Stein
in this connection: “Karl Marx’s articles on the Moselle and wood theft
questions… had the task of drawing public attention to the distressed economic
situation and to the defects of the
administrative bureaucracy, both of which were little known … among broader
circles due to the pressure of the pre-1848 censorship. But even today these
essays still deserve the attention of scientific research…” (Draper, ibid.,
footnote; italics added for attention).
At this stage of Marx’s political evolution, he still had the view that a third
element, which is neither of the state nor directly involved in private
interests, is needed to resolve the difficulty: the free press. This is all the
more necessary because of the tendency of the official “for demeaning the state
interests into his private affair, into interests from which all others are
excluded as laymen, so that even the crystal-clearest reality seems illusory to
him against the reality embedded in the documents under his nose…” Marx
deplored the tendency of the state bureaucracy “to look on the state as its
own private property” (Marx, 1842, quoted in Draper, op. cit., p.65-66).
From the analysis of these seemingly limited and simple
social situations, Marx proceeded to develop the concept of the state and to draw
lessons for the larger agenda for the
“battle for political democracy” (Draper, p.66), and the counter-positioning of
the “rights of individual people” (op. cit., p.67) against the rights of property
and the rights of the state:
“We vindicate the customary right of poverty [that is, the poor] … in all countries. We go even further and maintain that customary right in accordance with its nature can be only the right of this lowest, elementary mass which owns nothing” (Marx, quoted by Draper, op. cit., p.68; italics in original).
Marx claims this right for the poor on the ground that
"the privileged classes have long ago turned their customary rights (even the unreasonable ones) into statutory laws. …It is only the unprivileged whose customary rights have remained without the buttress of law; hence only in their case does such an appeal make sense” (Marx, 1842, quoted in Draper, op. cit., p.69).
“We vindicate the customary right of poverty [that is, the poor] … in all countries. We go even further and maintain that customary right in accordance with its nature can be only the right of this lowest, elementary mass which owns nothing” (Marx, quoted by Draper, op. cit., p.68; italics in original).
Marx claims this right for the poor on the ground that
"the privileged classes have long ago turned their customary rights (even the unreasonable ones) into statutory laws. …It is only the unprivileged whose customary rights have remained without the buttress of law; hence only in their case does such an appeal make sense” (Marx, 1842, quoted in Draper, op. cit., p.69).
The resonance of this argument with the justification and
rationale of the Forest Rights Act, 2006, is obvious. In fact, in another
(maybe not completely fortuitous) throwback to Marx’s concerns, the government
of the day held the forest service in India responsible for the rise of the
Naxalite menace (termed Left-Wing Extremism, LWE). Apart from mobilizing social
environmentalists to go around the country investigating the state of the
Forest Rights Act (the Saxena Committee, see Nitin Sethi’s report in the Times of India, 24 December 2010), a big
effort was mounted to establish gram sabha (community) rights on bamboo in the
forest (defined as a Minor Forest Produce, MFP, in the FRA, and hence the
property of the gram sabha under the Panchayati Raj legislation). The then
minister for environment & forests personally went to villages in the state
of Maharashtra to establish these rights by distribution of permit books to the
gram sabhas (a compromise arrived at to empower the communities while
maintaining some of the management regulations in the interests of long-term
viability of the crop) (see Times News Service report in the Times of India, 23 May 2011).
The founding-father of Indian forestry, Dietrich Brandis,
has some interesting comments on the forest situation in mid-19th
century Europe and the ‘revolution’ of 1848, which throw a slightly different
light on the value of some sacrifice in the immediate future in the longer term
interest; this obviously had (and has even today!) relevance to the Indian
situation, when social activists are pressing for the transfer of full rights
to the community:
“During the excited times of 1848, when the relaxation of
all restrictions was everywhere demanded in Germany, several villages in the
Kingdom of Würtemberg demanded permission to divide their communal forests
among the householders of the village. In a weak moment the Government
consented, the forests were divided and sold. The proceeds soon disappeared for
1848 was a year of excited popular assemblies, of drinking and carousing in
that part of the country. These villages I visited in 1865, and the people
complained bitterly of their poverty. The villages in the vicinity, that had
put up with the restrictions, which good forest management demands, were
prosperous and happy. No communal taxes, for the steady annual forest income
paid for the roads, lighting, schools and churches, and in addition yielded to
each householder firewood in abundance for the winter, and timber for repair of
their houses.” (Brandis, 1897 repr. 1994, p.150)
James C. Scott- Seeing Forestry Like a State
Among others, the case of ‘scientific’ forestry has been
analysed in detail by James C.Scott in his work Seeing Like a State, which has the telling sub-title How Certain Schemes to Improve the human
Condition Have Failed (Scott, 1998). In this book, Scott analyses certain
leading examples of how states strive to make society and social activities
more “legible”, by simplifying, standardizing, arranging, labeling,
categorizing, sedentarizing (restricting movements), and so on. Scott tries to
“provide a convincing logic behind the failure of some of the great utopian
social engineering schemes of the twentieth century” (op. cit., p.4).
The
examples chosen for detailed discussion are: state cadastral mapping to
systematize property holdings, taxation, etc.; ‘scientific’ forestry with
maximum productivity goals; highly planned new cities like Le Corbusier’s
design for Chandigarh, India; Soviet collectivization and “compulsory
villagization” in Tanzania (and in Ethiopia and Mozambique). A saving grace of
the work is that it is not restricted only to fiascoes of “high- modernism”
sponsored by the democratic states; he also mentions the ‘Great Leap Forward’
in China , and discusses in
detail collectivization in Russia
(Ch.6). Readers can obviously come up with other examples from theocratic and
nationalistic states, as well as communist dictatorships (the so-called People’s
Democratic Republics), which show the extreme disasters that unbridled good
intentions can cause.
Scott sees four elements as necessary to take these
high-sounding programmes to their final stage of a “full-fledged disaster”: the
“administrative ordering of nature and society” in an effort to make them
“legible” and hence, amenable to control, the “high-modernist ideology” with
its exaggerated faith in progress that has been “unscientifically
optimistic”; an “authoritarian state”
that is willing to use “the full weight of its coercive power” to implement these
designs; and a “prostrate civil society" that “lacks the capacity to
resist these plans” (op. cit., p.5). Their failure was because they were too
simplistic and rudimentary in their effort to define and systematize; they made
no allowance for the myriad “informal processes” and “improvisations in the
face of unpredictability”, the “local knowledge and know-how”, that are what
actually keep a “functioning social order” going (ibid., p.6).
We are more immediately concerned here with his comments
on the so-called scientific, sustained yield forestry model. Interestingly,
Scott states that this “scientific forestry” was originally developed from
about 1765 to 1800, largely in Prussia
and Saxony, and later spread to France ,
England and the US , and throughout the Third
World . Its advantages were the higher output of wood, shorter
rotations and hence higher economic return to forest land, thereby becoming the
standard for forest organizations “throughout the world”, transmitted for instance to India and Burma
by Dietrich Brandis, a German, and the US through Gifford Pinchot, “the second
chief forester of the United States”. “By the end of the nineteenth century,
German forestry science was hegemonic” (op. cit., p.19).
What, however, are the main objections to this type of
regimented production forestry, and what are the main conclusions reached by
Scott? One of the objections is that this “utopian dream of scientific
forestry… was not and could never be realized in practice”; in a litany of woes
that should bring a wry smile to the lips of any seasoned forester,
“Both nature and the human factor intervened. The existing
topography of the landscape and the vagaries of fire, storms, blights, climate
changes, insect populations, and disease conspired to thwart foresters and to
shape the actual forest. Also, given the insurmountable difficulties of
policing large forests, people living nearby typically continued to graze
animals, poach firewood and kindling, make charcoal, and use the forest in
other ways that prevented the foresters’ management plans from being fully realized.
Although, like all utopian schemes, it fell well short of attaining its goal,
the critical fact is that it did partly succeed in stamping the actual forest
with the imprint of its designs” (Scott, op. cit., p.19).
A more social objection (in reference to the encouragement
of Norway spruce or Scotch pine in place of German mixed forests) is that “The
monocropped forest was a disaster for peasants who were now deprived of all the
grazing, food, raw materials, and medicines that the earlier forest ecology had
afforded” (Scott, op. cit., p.19). “Radically simplified designs for natural
environments” seem “to court the same risks of failure” as those for social
organization (op. cit., p.7). “The failures and vulnerability of monocrop
commercial forests and genetically engineered, mechanized monocropping mimic
the failures of collective farms and planned cities. At this level, I am making
a case for the resilience of both social and natural diversity and a strong
case about the limits, in principle, of what we are likely to know about
complex, functioning order” (ibid.). Scott’s charge is that by focusing on the
revenue-yielding timber portion of the most valuable trees, modern forestry has
ignored “all those trees, bushes, and plants holding little or no potential for
state revenue” and even those that “might have been useful to the population
but whose value could not be converted into fiscal receipts” (op. cit., p.12).
Gone also were the vast majority of flora and fauna, “except those that
interested the crown’s gamekeepers”. All other uses of the forest e.g. for
food, sustenance of man and livestock, or cultural and religious values, “for
magic, worship, refuge, and so on”, were also ignored. “The forest as a habitat
disappears and is replaced by the forest as an economic resource to be managed
efficiently and profitably” (Scott, op. cit., p.13).
In the long run, Scott states, this model of the
“stripped-down forest” (op. cit., p.20) proved to be ecologically unsound and
unviable, as it “became painfully obvious only after the second rotation of conifers had been planted” (ibid., italics in
original), showing a drop of as much as two site quality classes due to the
imbalance in nutrient cycling. The excessive cleaning of undergrowth seems to
have contributed to “thinner and less nutritious soils” (ibid.). Same-age,
same-species stands not only left an “impoverished habitat” (p.21) but were also
vulnerable to large scale damages from pests, storm-fall etc. A similar list of burdens have been attributed to mono
culture and intensive (plantation) forestry in India, as well, and some of
these have indeed been collated by me as a
special paper during the training course in the Indian Forest
College , Dehradun (Dilip
Kumar, 1976).
This description of Scott’s follows the general lines of
the criticism of ‘scientific’ or organized state forestry leveled by old social
thinkers like Marx, or our modern social environmentalists like Madhav Gadgil
and Ramachandra Guha, Vandana Shiva, or Sharachchandra Lele and associates. In the collection of articles Deeper
Roots of Historical Injustice (Rights and Resources Initiative, 2012), Guha
comments that although the forest department was set up as early as 1864, it
was not until the 1980s that the social scientists began to systematically
examine (some would say, dissect!) its policies and programmes, in contrast
with their earlier scrutiny of other wings of the state like the revenue,
agriculture, irrigation and judicial. Perhaps
the most recent and impassioned statement of this position is contained in
Madhu Sarin’s chapter (Undoing Historical Injustice: Reclaiming Citizenship
Rights and Democratic Forest Governance through the Forest Rights Act) in Lele
& Menon (2014).
It may be appropriate to acknowledge here that the writings and other
advocacy of the social scientists and environmentalists have borne a sort of
fruit in the form of the Forest Rights Act 2006 (the full and formal title
being The Scheduled Tribes and Other
Forest Dwellers (Recognition of Forest Rights) Act, 2006, or ROFR Act), which seeks to transfer full control
of both individual and community rights over forest areas to the forest-dependent
people or communities. In a sense, the action research on the wood-theft
problem in German forests, initiated by Karl Marx in 1842, has come full circle
and rests now with the empowerment of the communities and their ostensible
‘liberation’ from the controlling hand of the state.
The Forest Rights Act (FRA) apparently goes beyond the Joint Forest Management (JFM) framework
drawn up by the forest department as a sort of compromise, although, as
gathered by the author during some village visits for a study (Dilip Kumar,
2014), at least in areas of settled agriculture (in Haryana, Karnataka, and
Tamil Nadu), the people themselves did
not differentiate so strongly between panchayati
raj institutions (PRIs) and department-led community-based organizations (CBOs). They usually prefer to have
the benefit of both types of institutions, especially as the PRIs stop at the
Village Panchayat (VP) level comprising of many large revenue villages, whereas
JFM committees and other sector-specific bodies are formed at a lower, hamlet
or settlement level, and are usually more responsive to the immediate needs of
smaller communities. Many communities express their need for collaborative institutions with state organs in addition to
the representative bodies of the PRIs (see my case study of the Haryana private
forests in the Economic & Political
Weekly, Dilip Kumar 2013; the full report is in the ISEC Monograph No.32, Dilip
Kumar 2014).[1]
It is not intended to take up a detailed analysis of these
topics here, as the instant purpose is to consider how the forest service
should respond in the objective situation of the present, rather than weighing
the rights and wrongs of this or that position or record of past actions. The
ensuing sections will take up some of the key issues, such as recruitment and
training, increasing the scientific content, and others that have been raised
as sketched out above, and attempt to present, and discuss, different points of
view as well as the author’s own perceptions.
[1]
Needless to say, the series of articles in the website www.forestmatters.in cover many of
these issues: discussion of village institutions is in the posts 14-18 (April
2015), and discussion of JFM, in the
context of Forest Landscape Restoration
(FLR), is in the posts 30-36 (January-February 2016); pdf versions of these are
posted at https://www.academia.edu/11997756/Decentralized_governance_and_forests_in_India
and https://www.academia.edu/21490696/Forest_Landscape_Restoration_in_India_Antecedents_experience_and_prognoses.
This article, as all others on this site, is the
intellectual property of the author, P.J.Dilip Kumar (IFS, Retired). You are
welcome to reproduce it with due acknowledgement.
References
Brandis,
Dietrich. 1897 (repr. 1994). Forestry in India .
Natraj Publishers, Dehradun.
Dilip Kumar, P.J.
1976. The Ecological Implications of
Intensive Culture in Forestry. Special paper submitted as part of the
Diploma in Forestry, 1974-76. (Typescript). February 1976. Indian Forest
College , Dehradun.
Dilip Kumar, P.J. 2013. Village communities and their common property forests. Economic & Political Weekly, Vol.xlviii,
No.35, 31 August 2013, pp.33-36.
Dilip Kumar, P.J. 2014. Managing India ’s
Forests: Village Communities, Panchayati Raj Institutions and the State.
Monograph #32 of the ISEC, Bangalore .
Draper, Hal.
1977. Karl Marx’s Theory of Revolution. Vol.I. State
and Bureaucracy. Monthly Review Press, New York , 1977. Reprinted 2011 by Aakar
Books for South Asia , Delhi-110091. Preview at
https://books.google.co.in/books?id=mC0UCgAAQBAJ
Gadgil, Madhav and
Ramachandra Guha.1992. This Fissured
Land. An Ecological History of India .
Oxford University
Press, New Delhi .
Gadgil,
Madhav and Ramachandra Guha. 2000. The
Use and Abuse of Nature. Oxford University
Press, New Delhi .
Guha,
Ramachandra. 2012. The Past and Future of Indian Forestry. Chapter I in Deeper Roots of Historical Injustice: Trends
and Challenges in the Forests of India . Published by Rights and
Resources Initiative, Washington ,
D.C. Available at www.rightsandresources.org/documents/files/doc_5589.pdf
Pinchot, Gifford. 1947
(1998). Breaking New Ground. Harcourt,
Brace, and Co., New York .
Commemorative edition published 1998 by Island Press, Washington , D.C.
Introductory essay by Char Miller and V.Alaric Sample.
Rights and
Resources Initiative. 2012. Deeper Roots
of Historical Injustice: Trends and Challenges in the Forests of India.Washington,
D.C. Available at www.rightsandresources.org/documents/files/doc_5589.pdf
Sarin, Madhu. 2014.
Undoing Historical Injustice: Reclaiming Citizenship Rights And Democratic
Forest Governance through the Forest Rights
Act. Chapter 3, in Lele and Menon (Eds.), 2014.
Scott, James C. 1998. Seeing Like a State. How Certain Schemes to
Improve the human Condition Have Failed. Yale University Press, New haven
and London .
Sethi, Nitin. Litmus
test for govt as NAC gets specific on forest rights. Times of India
(newspaper), 24 December 2010, New
Delhi .
Times News Service.
Ramesh moves to give tribals fair share in bamboo trade. Times of India
(newspaper), 23 March 2011, New Delhi .
No comments:
Post a Comment