Climate as a global commons
Granted that we should be conscious of the
limited capacity of the environment to absorb our emissions and repair the
damaging effects of excessive resource extraction and unsustainable use, what
should be our approach as a world community, and as an individual country? The
global atmosphere (and climate) is like a commons, with hundreds of independent
countries, thousands of corporate and other bodies, and billions of individual
families. There is no mechanism to impose the required controls on carbon
emissions on the independent countries, apart from a voluntary agreement. But
here the “logic of collective action” comes into operation (Olson, 1965. 1971).
Even the nation-state in modern times is not capable of supporting itself
solely on voluntary contributions, despite the strong emotional bonds that hold
the citizens together, and the benefits that they undeniably get in the
continuance of the state structure; the state has to impose compulsory taxes
and collect them with a firm hand. This is because, when there is a large
multitude of members, no one of them can be prevented from enjoying the
benefits of the organization; hence there will be an underlying incentive for
the individual to withhold his or her individual contribution as far as
possible, as long as it is reasonably certain that the contributions of the
myriad others will carry the organization forward. In fact, that would the rational thing to do, even if not
ethical or fair.
Another metaphor used to describe such
situations is the “tragedy of freedom in a commons” that Hardin (1968) talked
about many decades back. The problem with regulating use of a commons is that
private costs and benefits are mismatched with public ones: each person has to
incur a private cost that may be substantial from the individual point of view,
but the collective benefits are enjoyed by everybody, and moreover the
individual has little or no control on the actions of all the others, and hence
on the outcome. If the others choose to break the agreement and maximize their
private returns, our sincere individual may be left ‘holding the short stick’. My
PhD guide had a favourite story of his school days to illustrate this: they
would tell all the boys line up all the boys around the unheated swimming pool
on a winter morning, tell them to close their eyes and jump in on the count of
three, and when they opened their eyes, my professor would realize he was
the only
guy that had followed the order. No one likes to be taken advantage of in this
manner, so there is an in-built tendency for a mismatch between public
professions and actual behaviour, if the individual feels that they can get
away with it, or suspects that the majority of actors are intending to take
advantage.
In simple terms, when there are large
numbers of actors, and where the benefits are collective, or public goods, and
where no one person could be excluded from enjoying those benefits, it would be
the narrowly rational choice for individuals to avoid, as far as possible, the
incurring of costs on their side, while continuing to hold a cooperative public
posture so as to preserve their position as beneficiary. The consequent loss of
the cumulative benefits due to the individual’s covert actions will likely be
miniscule (after all, the individual’s contribution is a miniscule proportion,
and the enterprise will not break down even if there are a few defaulters), but
the return to the defaulter will be disproportionately high. Of course, this
sort of ‘free-riding’ will be penalised if it becomes chronic and the community
gets tired of it, so the individual may have to pay his dues once in a while,
just to maintain his membership in the community. The enterprise can still be
viable if the majority adhere to the rules, but sometimes a few bad apples can
spoil the whole lot.
Faced with this situation, one would have
to resort either to some control from outside (the state makes and enforces strict
laws, for example), or the resource is privatized so that both the costs and
benefits are incident on the same entity (i.e., externalities are
internalized). There is, however, a
possible third alternative in-between state control and privatization (Dilip Kumar,
1991), where the community and the state get together in a joint arrangement,
an example of the ‘nested’ institutions that Elinor Ostrom recommended as the
most conducive to successful management of common property resources (e.g., see
Ostrom, 1990).
This problem of ‘collective action’ is recognized by the “Climate
Change 2014 Synthesis Report” (IPCC 2014c) in the following words:
“Effective mitigation
will not be achieved if individual agents advance their own interests
independently. Climate change has the characteristics of a collective
action problem at the global scale… Cooperative responses, including
international cooperation, are therefore required…The evidence suggests that
outcomes seen as equitable can lead to more effective cooperation.” (IPCC, 2014c,
p.76; emphasis in original).
In the Indian forest scenario, for example,
this principle has been institutionalised in the Joint Forest Management (JFM),
regime wherein the state forests are managed in partnership with the
communities, and conversely, communities also find it more effective to protect
even their own forest resources if there is support from the state (e.g. Dilip
Kumar, 2013).
Choosing between domestic interests and global concerns
In our climate change scenario, what would
be the rational choice for a country like India, given this ‘logic of
collective action’? We need to be clear about two things: firstly, if India were to
limit its GHG emissions (say at today’s levels), what would be the impact on
global climate change? India contributes a sizeable quantum of current
emissions (because, like China, it has a huge population, although at very low
per capita levels of consumption and, consequently, emissions), and it may be
thought that a cap on aggregate emissions at the current level would have a
discernible impact, but in the world situation this may be masked because other
countries will continue to increase their emissions. Moreover in spite of such caps, India and other
economies will still be adding sizeably every year to the carbon load in the
atmosphere. Consider, for example, India ’s contribution to global CO2
from the “energy and transformation industries” in 2007 according to NATCOM-2
(Government of India, 2012): taking the figure as 749,617 Gg, or 749.6 mta (or
0.7496 Gt per annum), it constitutes a small (if not exactly negligible)
fraction of the annual contribution of 49 Gt in 2010 (globally) referred to
above. Even if India wants to double the energy production, say over a period
of 10 years, this will add only around 0.075 Gt to the annual addition to the
global GHGs, compared to the annual increase of 1 Gt per year globally (see
above). This is only 7.5% of the
increase in annual CO2 accretions, but CO2 levels will
still be increasing year to year, unless some great new sink or method of
fixing it could be found.
In other words, India by itself will not be able to
contribute meaningfully to the resolution of the GHG problem just by curbing
energy production at current levels, or influence the actions of the rest of
the world (this is not a situation where the famous moral force of Gandhism can
be applied!). So India
will have to proceed as if the rest of the world is going to keep increasing
its emissions in the near future. If India were to make any voluntary,
unilateral sacrifices now, it would have neither the imagined benefits of the
reduced carbon loads, nor the benefits of a stronger economy and greater world
influence in the future. Indeed, the very fact that a huge population like India
foregoes its present entitlements, will only prompt other countries to
appropriate that share for themselves.
Therefore, it is not a rational strategy
for a country like India
to make any unilateral cuts or promises at the present juncture, and this has
rightly been our position in the world climate conferences, with the only
concession made that we will never exceed the current per capita emission levels of the industrial countries. These, of
course, are levels we will never even aspire to: as has been repeated often
enough, we will need another seven planet Earths if all the world’s people were
to consume at the western levels.
We will, however, be aspiring to some
intermediate level of consumption, which will require a many-fold increase in
the production of energy and various other sectors. On the other hand, India
has the world’s largest population of poor, with low quality of life
indicators; it has to vigorously pursue its course of positive affirmation to
set right the historical wrongs to sections of the population, and increase
investment in public health and medicare, education, communications, skills
development, job creation, etc., and at the same time play its geo-political
role as one of the largest economies of the world. The experience of the last
general election suggests that the masses also are looking for something beyond
just subsidized food and other doles, and there is a huge middle class that has
aspirations of making it in the modern economy.
This does not mean, however, that we should
be indifferent to the issues of environmental degradation in our own sphere,
quite regardless of the world climate conferences (just as, indeed, high carbon emitters like the
developed west would be well advised to reduce per capita consumption levels,
not for the sake of the global good, but in the interests of the health and
well-being of their own citizens).
Indeed, this has been the
strategy adopted by our governments over the past decades: while insisting on
our share of the global carbon cake, in terms of increasing per capita consumption
(and emissions) levels, we have also steadily taken many steps to improving the
sustainability of our development process and mitigating damage to our own
environment. Of course, the complaint is that we are strong in legislation, but
weak in enforcement, as the numerous articles in the popular media, and the
spate of environmental cases in the courts, attest. This lag between intent and
action, however, is to be expected during the catch-up phase, when all output
levels are being racked up many-fold. In keeping with the form of the Kuznets
curve, we may expect to see a lessening of this gap and an improvement in both
the incidence of poverty and the laxity
in enforcing environmental safeguards as GDP per capita progresses beyond a
certain level (see Lomborg, op. cit., p.177 for examples of this in the context
of particle pollution and SO2 pollution).
In the meanwhile, it will be an advisable strategy
to identify the points of greatest importance that need to be addressed to keep
our country’s environmental systems and natural resource base intact in
anticipation of those future levels of relative prosperity. Some of these
crucial sectors are our water resources, our forests and grasslands, our
biodiversity and wildlife habitats, our marine resources and coastlands, our wetlands
(especially mangroves), our catchment areas in the hills, and our urban air
quality. While we need to accelerate our development process, we also need to
ensure grater participation in the fruits of that development, by rapidly
improving public education and public health, communications and transport
facilities, raising skill levels and employability, minimizing displacement of
people and ensuring proper rehabilitation where displacement is unavoidable,
just as with diversion of natural habitats.
(This article series is based on my paper
prepared for the “International Conference on Climate Change and
Social-Ecological-Economic Interface-Building”, May 20-21, 2015, organized by
the Centre for Ecological Economics and Natural Resources (CEENR), Institute
for Social and Economic Change (ISEC), Nagarbhavi, Bengaluru-560072, India.
Uploaded at: www.academia.edu/13402458/...)
Keywords
Climate change, green-house gases,
development strategy, natural resources, forest, carbon sequestration, IPCC,
REDD
References
Dilip Kumar, P.J. 1991. Between common
property and state monopoly: the institutional context of wasteland management
in India .
In “Managing the Village Commons”, Proceedings of national workshop 15-16
December, 1991, Bhubaneswar ,
Orissa. IIFM, Bhopal .
Dilip Kumar, P.J. 2013. Village Communities
and Their Common Property Forests .
Economic & Political Weekly, Vol.
XLVIII, No.35, August 31, 2013, p.33-36.
Government
of India .
2012. India . Second National Communication to the United Nations Framework
Convention on Climate Change. New
Delhi .
Hardin,
G. 1968. The Tragedy of the Commons. Science,
162, p.1243-1248.
Lomborg, Bjørn. (1998) 2001. The Skeptical Environmentalist. Measuring
the Real State of the World. Cambridge University
Press , UK
and New York .
Olson, Mancur. 1965, 1971. The Logic of Collective Action. Public Goods
and the Theory of Groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
(USA ).
Ostrom, Elinor. 1990. Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action.
Cambridge Universities Press, Cambridge .
No comments:
Post a Comment